Monday, 15 August 2016

THE QUEEN, RATIONALITY AND ECONOMICS

THE QUEEN, RATIONALITY AND ECONOMICS

          Once upon a time there was this cobbler, following generations of his family working in his shoemaking and shoe-repair shop – though it was becoming more and more ‘down at heel’ as business got a little worse each year. Unfortunately the market had changed; not only were mass-produced shoes now cheaper than any he could make, but repairing them became irrelevant as they were glued rather than sewn together and so easier to throw away than repair. The cobbler despaired: was this the end of a long family tradition? Then a miracle occurred: the arrival of a substantial legacy from a distant aged and now-deceased great aunt. With this, the cobbler cheered up, determined to make a new start. He had his shoe-repair shop completely revamped as a coffee-serving glitzy tattoo emporium plus ear nose lip nipple and tongue piercer and nail bar. This rang all the right bells to the extent that our now ex-cobbler was able to build up a chain of outlets which in time became a nationwide business. Success had arrived with modish versatility.
          Such it seems is the case with modern and post-crisis economics. Once, though still flourishing in academia, the ‘dismal science’ was becoming side-lined as business, governments and the media came increasingly to seek the advice of successful entrepreneurs and traders, a number with the highly-popular MBAs, rather than bona fide economists. Whole swathes of the business community as well as government and news organs were dropping economists from the payroll as they turned to those they considered offered more relevant expertise.
          As economics ceased to be a progressive theoretical science about 150 years ago it gave up ‘the larger picture’ (or ‘grand narrative’) in favour of a more piecemeal, nuts-and-bolts positivist approach to the economy utilising ever-more-sophisticated econometrics in the process. Unfortunately this placed economists on the same level with more hands-on MBA-type operators and speculators who knew more about the practical side because they got their hands dirty. Economists, however, with remnants of a loftier and pseudo-theoretical approach, were carrying too much baggage, but without sufficient practical experience, to compete successfully with those who had never seen themselves as scientists or theoreticians in the first place. All the economists could offer in addition were expensive jargon-trimmings of little use to business firms competing fiercely for profits. A bit like entering a Rolls Royce for Formula One. A saying went round to the effect that when you put two economists together you got three opinions. Recently economics students up and down the UK have been in revolt against university economics departments which they accuse of offering them a narrow-minded and irrelevant curriculum which bears no relation to the crisis-ridden economy they – and we – live under. The Queen (who decides just how impartial she will be on any given occasion), when on a tour of the London School of Economics after the crisis of 2008, asked economists why no one had foreseen it, and they were rather embarrassingly and apologetically unable to come up with an answer. The Queen’s point, it would seem, was how useful could an economic science be that failed utterly to anticipate the biggest economic crisis since the Great Depression? (In fact it had been anticipated by a few, but we’ll come to them later.) Had Elizabeth II been Henry VIII one could imagine the profs shaking in their shoes as the gallows awaited. They shuddered enough as it was.
          Miraculously, from this nadir in fortunes the dismal science has been transformed into an all-singing, all-dancing science. The theatre was saved by a smash-hit musical! For when your science is holed up in a corner of wretchedness and irrelevance, the thing to do is to go for broke – that is, to rejuvenate your science by making it take over all the sciences. Imperialism abroad revives prosperity at home. The vacuity of your own science lends it a positive advantage when absorbing all others: the ringmaster need not have the talents and skills of his circus performers, presenting all the better for having no particular talent of his own.
          The new economics has displaced postmodernism as the absorber of whole disciplines through the medium of the verbal sleight-of-hand.
          The herald of this development was a celebrated best-seller of 2005, Freakonomics, by Steven Levitt and Stephen J Dubner, which was described as ‘melding pop culture with economics’. At bottom (and I have to quote this from Wikipedia) the book accepts ‘the standard neoclassical microeconomic model of rational utility-maximization’. Light-hearted and funny in tone, it deftly pursues the economics of, for example, cheating, drug-dealing, data-mining and myriad other human possibilities. However, its authors have been criticised for writing a work of sociology-stroke-criminology rather than economics, and some of the mathematics used also – in the opinion of those mathematical scientists who have looked into the matter – appears to be ropey in places. Ariel Rubenstein, an Israeli economist, presciently (from the perspective of this article) called the book an example of ‘academic imperialism’. While Arnold King referred to it as ‘amateur sociology’. But this has not stopped it from becoming almost a household title, as it were, spawning sequels, web sites, conferences, games and generating a load of publicity for the new economics of everything. No more dismalism here. Everything is potentially comprehensible through applied economics. Though not necessarily the economy itself. It required someone else to bring the weight of ‘orthodox economics’ to bear upon the new Renaissance.
          With regard to the Queen’s question to economists, Andrew Lilico, an economist writing for the Daily Telegraph of January 23rd, 2014 (‘Economists are nearly always right about things despite what you may think’) replies that 
Orthodox economics tells us that it is impossible to predict significant financial crises in advance or else everyone would predict them and trade off that and so they wouldn’t happen.

In fact, the 2007-08 crisis was predicted as imminent by, amongst others, Professor Nouriel (‘Dr Doom’) Roubini , of New York University’s Stern School of Business, as well as by various Marxist economic commentators such as Michael Roberts and Alan Woods. For example, Woods wrote this for a Marxist website back on November 14th, 2000:
The scenario is, in fact, much more reminiscent of the 1920s than the beginning of the post-1945 economic upswing. The collapse of the present boom will usher in a turbulent period of crisis with far-reaching consequences for the whole world. (‘Marxism and the Theory of “Long Waves”’, www.marxist.com/marxism-theory-long-waves-kondratiev 14100.htm)

Orthodox economists were perhaps so preoccupied with the belief that significant crises are inherently unpredictable that these various doom-sayers were entirely ignored.
          Moreover, significant financial crises have for so long been a constant recurrence in their dozens since at least 1819 (some bigger than others) that it would seem they were all too predictable, and perhaps growing more so.
          And people do respond to pessimistic predictions without this necessarily voiding the oncoming crisis. Joseph Kennedy, for one, pulled all his money out of the New York Stock Exchange just before the Great Crash of October, 1929, which left him a rich man, able later to fund his son Jack all the way to the US presidency; Kennedy was not alone in his prudence but the Crash came about all the same.
          Lilico seems not to have encountered the economic herd instinct. One could post a mathematician in a stall outside the entrance to every gaming casino in the world with displays showing the actual odds of winning against the house. Assuming management goons would not have these mathematicians quickly and forcibly removed, it is likely that members of the gaming public would flood in all the same. I am some 300 times more likely to be struck by lightning on a sunny day than to win the top prize of the National Lottery (fortunately the Lottery offers lesser prizes which lowers the odds on winning something). Millions of people are not taken in and gamble nothing at all; but millions of others do and get back nothing, or enough perhaps to sustain the habit but no more. Of course a tiny number of outright winners serve as publicity to fuel the drive.
          The Stock Market works to large extent on this optimistic herd mentality, driven as investment capital is to be invested somewhere, somehow.  But is this ‘rational’ behaviour? Lilico: ‘economics is the discipline that tells you why behaviours make sense’. So why did buyers go on buying shares when virtually every perceptive observer knew that the New York Stock Exchange had divorced itself from the economic realities of the United States since mid-1929? (Even the Federal Reserve Board had had interest rates raised in a vain attempt to stem borrowing against spiralling speculation.)
          I would have thought that seeing people running away from the burning Twin Towers on 9/11 could better tell you why behaviours make sense. Though Lilico’s economics would make better sense of behaviours too if its subject were shown to be fundamentally irrational, not rational.
          Rationality has been devalued since the days of Descartes (‘clear and distinct ideas’) to mean a concept of material gain: you are ‘rational’ if you pursue a profit for gain as opposed to going for a loss. So this writes off the Buddha, Jesus Christ and St Francis of Assisi. A ‘rational’ Nurse Cavell would have turned state’s evidence.  Mozart was a hopeless case: an avid and entirely non-rational gambler, he died poor. Never mind the music.
          Let us look further at rationality.
          You are a clergyman with a wife and family and you have lost your faith. Now, in your 50s, it is not easy for you to think of qualifying for and being employed in another career. So what do you do? Do you drive your family into destitution or do you continue paying lip-service and going through the motions of something you care nothing for and are even against?  The latter is, surely, the rational course, even if it is the wasted life.
          Let us tighten the screws of authority.
          Let us suppose you are a citizen of Gestapo-run Nazi Germany. Is it rational to hide a Jewish family in your loft? Is it not more rational to toe the Party line, holding entirely Nazi views and professing undying allegiance to Hitler with every salute whether or not you join the Party? And to gain brownie-points by denouncing a neighbour you learn has hidden a Jew? It is easy to see which course here is the most rational.
          Is it not more rational to rob a pension-fund legally than hold up a bank illegally?
          Rationality in Lilico’s economic concept he calls an ‘axiom’ – that is, ‘an accepted statement or proposition regarded as being self-evidently true’ (Oxford Concise Dictionary):
No behaviour can prove that people aren’t, in fact, rational, because for an orthodox economist the only kind of explanation of any behaviour that counts as an economic explanation is an explanation that makes sense of that behaviour – that shows why the behaviour is rational.

(I have trouble with what I suspect is circular reasoning here, but let that pass.) In other words, no explanation that includes irrational behaviour as an economic explanation can make sense of the behaviour; thus all economic behaviour is rational. So if you explain that the capital system is rational or based on rational motivation and calculation you can eliminate irrationality from it.
          But suppose the whole of the capital system is irrational, however rational its working parts?
          Suppose the working parts of Nazi German industry were highly rational while the Nazi power system in toto was irrational?
          Suppose that concentration camps were organised and run on strictly rational premises but that the concentration camp system as a whole was insane?
          Suppose that the need for profit and gain in so far as it is potentially insatiable is not only irrational but insane? Suppose this because both the natural and the human environment are finite whereas capital expansion is premised on infinity? This is the capital that hated the introduction of the ten-hour working day and child labour restrictions, and worldwide is continuing to try and undermine the moral authority of both measures. Investments must ever achieve a higher return than before, and then a still-higher return, and so on ad infinitum. Is this a self-evident axiom? Is it rational? Or is it insane? It used to be said that Hitler was insane because he wanted to rule the world. But can a system not also be insane for attempting to do the same thing, which is what capital must attempt, the rule of the world (and outer space besides)?
          Industries rational; the whole system irrational. Production rational; markets competitively irrational. Thus is shown the Fallacy of Composition: that the whole is merely made up of the sum of its parts. But a government is not a business firm or a domestic household writ large; it is an entirely different entity from either, even as it is of a country made up of firms and households. In science, water comes from the combination of two flammable gases, neither of which on its own is the least bit ‘watery’. 9+6=15, but 15 is neither 9 nor 6. A business firm may be run rationally to maximise productivity; but the market system of which it is a part is both anarchic and irrational. The whole is nothing like the parts even as the parts make up the whole.
          Lilico’s system of rationality applies to the running of individual businesses in pursuit of higher productivity but it is misapplied as a characterisation of the competitive system taken as a whole, which plunders the earth of its resources and humanity of its well-being solely for the sake of investing in pursuit of more wealth and power, and more again. If it cannot achieve these ends it drops all interest in achieving any other by the way, such as involvement in beauty, truth and freedom. None of which is rational, according to Lilico’s premises.
          As for academic imperialism, we learn from Lilico that economics has superseded the science of psychology, specifically behavioural psychology: ‘But economics is the discipline that seeks to explain why I raised my left arm in terms that make sense to me, given my objectives and beliefs.’ So long as you are in it for some personal economic gain, any aspect of your behaviour is thus explicable. This is the true homo economicus.
          We are back to that old ‘propensity to truck, barter and exchange’, known to the classical political economists of the 18th century, which explained a priori all human behaviour and psychology. For it all makes sense in a society that is entirely commodified, including the commodification of all values and ideas, the commodification of the entire natural environment.
          In this sense – both ultra-modern and very antediluvian anthropologically – is Lilico the herald of a new science of everything, provided that ‘everything’ is up for sale and able to render a money profit. Increasingly, not much in the world now lies outside that. Meanwhile, the new economics is finally freed from any responsibility to do with bringing about a reversal of worldwide economic instability and stagnation, because ‘rationality’ in this case becomes a form of insulation from troubling episodes and portents of disaster. Just as the Catholic clerics refused to look through Galileo’s telescope because it was impious to do so. What I don’t know or refuse to examine is not worth knowing – and may even be damnable: ‘By disregard they sought completeness.’ [1]  The new economics must perforce take on all rationality as it rises to the challenge of justifying the reality of a Ptolemaic solar system called capitalism. Lilico’s final words:
The insights orthodox economics will eventually produce in reaction to the financial crisis will advance our social and economic life and prosperity even further than economics has done already. For good economists, given time and sound theory, are almost always right about everything.

Which might also be said for astrologers and theologians, whose premises can never be questioned – ‘axiomatic’ as they are in their own way. But more like the theologians than the astrologers, who actually do predict things.
          Only today in The Guardian I read this by Paul Mason: that our present poor working practices
typically prevail where a political system is stacked so heavily against the workforce that there can be no countervailing voice, and where an economic model in its infancy requires the urgent extraction of profit through coercion.
You need under-resourced inspection agencies; unions forbidden to organise; and a ready supply of cheap labour. So it was in the England of George III, so it is in Britain in the second decade of the 21st century. (Guardian G2, 26.07.16, p.5.)

This makes Andrew Lilico with his ‘rational’ orthodox economics lo0k like no one so much as the immortal Dr Pangloss (everything is for the best in the best of all possible worlds). I flatter myself perhaps as, in a small way, Mr Lilico’s Voltaire.  




[1] Charles Fort, The Books of Charles Fort (The Book of the  Damned) New York 1959, 248.
            Once upon a time there was this cobbler, following generations of his family working in his shoemaking and shoe-repair shop – though it was becoming more and more ‘down at heel’ as business got a little worse each year. Unfortunately the market had changed; not only were mass-produced shoes now cheaper than any he could make, but repairing them became irrelevant as they were glued rather than sewn together and so easier to throw away than repair. The cobbler despaired: was this the end of a long family tradition? Then a miracle occurred: the arrival of a substantial legacy from a distant aged and now-deceased great aunt. With this, the cobbler cheered up, determined to make a new start. He had his shoe-repair shop completely revamped as a coffee-serving glitzy tattoo emporium plus ear nose lip nipple and tongue piercer and nail bar. This rang all the right bells to the extent that our now ex-cobbler was able to build up a chain of outlets which in time became a nationwide business. Success had arrived with modish versatility.
            Such it seems is the case with modern and post-crisis economics. Once, though still flourishing in academia, the ‘dismal science’ was becoming side-lined as business, governments and the media came increasingly to seek the advice of successful entrepreneurs and traders, a number with the highly-popular MBAs, rather than bona fide economists. Whole swathes of the business community as well as government and news organs were dropping economists from the payroll as they turned to those they considered offered more relevant expertise.
            As economics ceased to be a progressive theoretical science about 150 years ago it gave up ‘the larger picture’ (or ‘grand narrative’) in favour of a more piecemeal, nuts-and-bolts positivist approach to the economy utilising ever-more-sophisticated econometrics in the process. Unfortunately this placed economists on the same level with more hands-on MBA-type operators and speculators who knew more about the practical side because they got their hands dirty. Economists, however, with remnants of a loftier and pseudo-theoretical approach, were carrying too much baggage, but without sufficient practical experience, to compete successfully with those who had never seen themselves as scientists or theoreticians in the first place. All the economists could offer in addition were expensive jargon-trimmings of little use to business firms competing fiercely for profits. A bit like entering a Rolls Royce for Formula One. A saying went round to the effect that when you put two economists together you got three opinions. Recently economics students up and down the UK have been in revolt against university economics departments which they accuse of offering them a narrow-minded and irrelevant curriculum which bears no relation to the crisis-ridden economy they – and we – live under. The Queen (who decides just how impartial she will be on any given occasion), when on a tour of the London School of Economics after the crisis of 2008, asked economists why no one had foreseen it, and they were rather embarrassingly and apologetically unable to come up with an answer. The Queen’s point, it would seem, was how useful could an economic science be that failed utterly to anticipate the biggest economic crisis since the Great Depression? (In fact it had been anticipated by a few, but we’ll come to them later.) Had Elizabeth II been Henry VIII one could imagine the profs shaking in their shoes as the gallows awaited. They shuddered enough as it was.
            Miraculously, from this nadir in fortunes the dismal science has been transformed into an all-singing, all-dancing science. The theatre was saved by a smash-hit musical! For when your science is holed up in a corner of wretchedness and irrelevance, the thing to do is to go for broke – that is, to rejuvenate your science by making it take over all the sciences. Imperialism abroad revives prosperity at home. The vacuity of your own science lends it a positive advantage when absorbing all others: the ringmaster need not have the talents and skills of his circus performers, presenting all the better for having no particular talent of his own.
            The new economics has displaced postmodernism as the absorber of whole disciplines through the medium of the verbal sleight-of-hand.
            The herald of this development was a celebrated best-seller of 2005, Freakonomics, by Steven Levitt and Stephen J Dubner, which was described as ‘melding pop culture with economics’. At bottom (and I have to quote this from Wikipedia) the book accepts ‘the standard neoclassical microeconomic model of rational utility-maximization’. Light-hearted and funny in tone, it deftly pursues the economics of, for example, cheating, drug-dealing, data-mining and myriad other human possibilities. However, its authors have been criticised for writing a work of sociology-stroke-criminology rather than economics, and some of the mathematics used also – in the opinion of those mathematical scientists who have looked into the matter – appears to be ropey in places. Ariel Rubenstein, an Israeli economist, presciently (from the perspective of this article) called the book an example of ‘academic imperialism’. While Arnold King referred to it as ‘amateur sociology’. But this has not stopped it from becoming almost a household title, as it were, spawning sequels, web sites, conferences, games and generating a load of publicity for the new economics of everything. No more dismalism here. Everything is potentially comprehensible through applied economics. Though not necessarily the economy itself. It required someone else to bring the weight of ‘orthodox economics’ to bear upon the new Renaissance.
            With regard to the Queen’s question to economists, Andrew Lilico, an economist writing for the Daily Telegraph of January 23rd, 2014 (‘Economists are nearly always right about things despite what you may think’) replies that 
Orthodox economics tells us that it is impossible to predict significant financial crises in advance or else everyone would predict them and trade off that and so they wouldn’t happen.

In fact, the 2007-08 crisis was predicted as imminent by, amongst others, Professor Nouriel (‘Dr Doom’) Roubini , of New York University’s Stern School of Business, as well as by various Marxist economic commentators such as Michael Roberts and Alan Woods. For example, Woods wrote this for a Marxist website back on November 14th, 2000:
The scenario is, in fact, much more reminiscent of the 1920s than the beginning of the post-1945 economic upswing. The collapse of the present boom will usher in a turbulent period of crisis with far-reaching consequences for the whole world. (‘Marxism and the Theory of “Long Waves”’, www.marxist.com/marxism-theory-long-waves-kondratiev 14100.htm) (now discontinued)

Orthodox economists were perhaps so preoccupied with the belief that significant crises are inherently unpredictable that these various doom-sayers were entirely ignored.
            Moreover, significant financial crises have for so long been a constant recurrence in their dozens since at least 1819 (some bigger than others) that it would seem they were all too predictable, and perhaps growing more so.
            And people do respond to pessimistic predictions without this necessarily voiding the oncoming crisis. Joseph Kennedy, for one, pulled all his money out of the New York Stock Exchange just before the Great Crash of October, 1929, which left him a rich man, able later to fund his son Jack all the way to the US presidency; Kennedy was not alone in his prudence but the Crash came about all the same.
            Lilico seems not to have encountered the economic herd instinct. One could post a mathematician in a stall outside the entrance to every gaming casino in the world with displays showing the actual odds of winning against the house. Assuming management goons would not have these mathematicians quickly and forcibly removed, it is likely that members of the gaming public would flood in all the same. I am some 300 times more likely to be struck by lightning on a sunny day than to win the top prize of the National Lottery (fortunately the Lottery offers lesser prizes which lowers the odds on winning something). Millions of people are not taken in and gamble nothing at all; but millions of others do and get back nothing, or enough perhaps to sustain the habit but no more. Of course a tiny number of outright winners serve as publicity to fuel the drive.
            The Stock Market works to large extent on this optimistic herd mentality, driven as investment capital is to be invested somewhere, somehow.  But is this ‘rational’ behaviour? Lilico: ‘economics is the discipline that tells you why behaviours make sense’. So why did buyers go on buying shares when virtually every perceptive observer knew that the New York Stock Exchange had divorced itself from the economic realities of the United States since mid-1929? (Even the Federal Reserve Board had had interest rates raised in a vain attempt to stem borrowing against spiralling speculation.)
            I would have thought that seeing people running away from the burning Twin Towers on 9/11 could better tell you why behaviours make sense. Though Lilico’s economics would make better sense of behaviours too if its subject were shown to be fundamentally irrational, not rational.
            Rationality has been devalued since the days of Descartes (‘clear and distinct ideas’) to mean a concept of material gain: you are ‘rational’ if you pursue a profit for gain as opposed to going for a loss. So this writes off the Buddha, Jesus Christ and St Francis of Assisi. A ‘rational’ Nurse Cavell would have turned state’s evidence.  Mozart was a hopeless case: an avid and entirely non-rational gambler, he died poor. Never mind the music.
            Let us look further at rationality.
            You are a clergyman with a wife and family and you have lost your faith. Now, in your 50s, it is not easy for you to think of qualifying for and being employed in another career. So what do you do? Do you drive your family into destitution or do you continue paying lip-service and going through the motions of something you care nothing for and are even against?  The latter is, surely, the rational course, even if it is the wasted life.
            Let us tighten the screws of authority.
            Let us suppose you are a citizen of Gestapo-run Nazi Germany. Is it rational to hide a Jewish family in your loft? Is it not more rational to toe the Party line, holding entirely Nazi views and professing undying allegiance to Hitler with every salute whether or not you join the Party? And to gain brownie-points by denouncing a neighbour you learn has hidden a Jew? It is easy to see which course here is the most rational.
            Is it not more rational to rob a pension-fund legally than hold up a bank illegally?
            Rationality in Lilico’s economic concept he calls an ‘axiom’ – that is, ‘an accepted statement or proposition regarded as being self-evidently true’ (Oxford Concise Dictionary):
No behaviour can prove that people aren’t, in fact, rational, because for an orthodox economist the only kind of explanation of any behaviour that counts as an economic explanation is an explanation that makes sense of that behaviour – that shows why the behaviour is rational.

(I have trouble with what I suspect is circular reasoning here, but let that pass.) In other words, no explanation that includes irrational behaviour as an economic explanation can make sense of the behaviour; thus all economic behaviour is rational. So if you explain that the capital system is rational or based on rational motivation and calculation you can eliminate irrationality from it.
            But suppose the whole of the capital system is irrational, however rational its working parts?
            Suppose the working parts of Nazi German industry were highly rational while the Nazi power system in toto was irrational?
            Suppose that concentration camps were organised and run on strictly rational premises but that the concentration camp system as a whole was insane?
            Suppose that the need for profit and gain in so far as it is potentially insatiable is not only irrational but insane? Suppose this because both the natural and the human environment are finite whereas capital expansion is premised on infinity? This is the capital that hated the introduction of the ten-hour working day and child labour restrictions, and worldwide is continuing to try and undermine the moral authority of both measures. Investments must ever achieve a higher return than before, and then a still-higher return, and so on ad infinitum. Is this a self-evident axiom? Is it rational? Or is it insane? It used to be said that Hitler was insane because he wanted to rule the world. But can a system not also be insane for attempting to do the same thing, which is what capital must attempt, the rule of the world (and outer space besides)?
            Industries rational; the whole system irrational. Production rational; markets competitively irrational. Thus is shown the Fallacy of Composition: that the whole is merely made up of the sum of its parts. But a government is not a business firm or a domestic household writ large; it is an entirely different entity from either, even as it is of a country made up of firms and households. In science, water comes from the combination of two flammable gases, neither of which on its own is the least bit ‘watery’. 9+6=15, but 15 is neither 9 nor 6. A business firm may be run rationally to maximise productivity; but the market system of which it is a part is both anarchic and irrational. The whole is nothing like the parts even as the parts make up the whole.
            Lilico’s system of rationality applies to the running of individual businesses in pursuit of higher productivity but it is misapplied as a characterisation of the competitive system taken as a whole, which plunders the earth of its resources and humanity of its well-being solely for the sake of investing in pursuit of more wealth and power, and more again. If it cannot achieve these ends it drops all interest in achieving any other by the way, such as involvement in beauty, truth and freedom. None of which is rational, according to Lilico’s premises.
            As for academic imperialism, we learn from Lilico that economics has superseded the science of psychology, specifically behavioural psychology: ‘But economics is the discipline that seeks to explain why I raised my left arm in terms that make sense to me, given my objectives and beliefs.’ So long as you are in it for some personal economic gain, any aspect of your behaviour is thus explicable. This is the true homo economicus.
            We are back to that old ‘propensity to truck, barter and exchange’, known to the classical political economists of the 18th century, which explained a priori all human behaviour and psychology. For it all makes sense in a society that is entirely commodified, including the commodification of all values and ideas, the commodification of the entire natural environment.
            In this sense – both ultra-modern and very antediluvian anthropologically – is Lilico the herald of a new science of everything, provided that ‘everything’ is up for sale and able to render a money profit. Increasingly, not much in the world now lies outside that. Meanwhile, the new economics is finally freed from any responsibility to do with bringing about a reversal of worldwide economic instability and stagnation, because ‘rationality’ in this case becomes a form of insulation from troubling episodes and portents of disaster. Just as the Catholic clerics refused to look through Galileo’s telescope because it was impious to do so. What I don’t know or refuse to examine is not worth knowing – and may even be damnable: ‘By disregard they sought completeness.’ [1]  The new economics must perforce take on all rationality as it rises to the challenge of justifying the reality of a Ptolemaic solar system called capitalism. Lilico’s final words:
The insights orthodox economics will eventually produce in reaction to the financial crisis will advance our social and economic life and prosperity even further than economics has done already. For good economists, given time and sound theory, are almost always right about everything.

Which might also be said for astrologers and theologians, whose premises can never be questioned – ‘axiomatic’ as they are in their own way. But more like the theologians than the astrologers, who actually do predict things.
            Only today in The Guardian I read this by Paul Mason: that our present poor working practices
typically prevail where a political system is stacked so heavily against the workforce that there can be no countervailing voice, and where an economic model in its infancy requires the urgent extraction of profit through coercion.
You need under-resourced inspection agencies; unions forbidden to organise; and a ready supply of cheap labour. So it was in the England of George III, so it is in Britain in the second decade of the 21st century. (Guardian G2, 26.07.16, p.5.)

This makes Andrew Lilico with his ‘rational’ orthodox economics lo0k like no one so much as the immortal Dr Pangloss (everything is for the best in the best of all possible worlds). I flatter myself perhaps as, in a small way, Mr Lilico’s Voltaire.  




[1] Charles Fort, The Books of Charles Fort (The Book of the  Damned) New York 1959, 248.

No comments:

Post a Comment