HA-JOON CHANG: Caveat Emptor!
Known through his Guardian
contributions but also for his bestseller 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About
Capitalism, Ha-Joon Chang is a lecturer in economics at Cambridge University. In
terms of theory he would appear to be something of a Left Keynesian, believing
that capitalism should be tempered by enlightened state intervention and
brought towards a more equitable society. Meanwhile, he is an engaging writer well-suited
to the task of providing Economics: The User’s Guide, a Pelican Introduction,
for the layperson (2014).
Up
to a point.
Amongst those he thanks in his Acknowledgements
are Leftwing and sometime fellow Guardian columnists Seumas Milne (now working
to get Corbyn’s Labour elected) and Aditya Chakrabortty, as well as eminent
Marxist economist and Leftwing Greek politician Costas Lapavitsas, author of
Profiting Without Producing (2013).
For all that, Ha-Joon Chang is
surprisingly ill-informed about Marx and Marxism, one of his thumbnail sketches
of all the various economic schools from Classic Political Economy to the
Austrian School, Keynesianism and Neo-Classicism, etc. For each, he weighs up
their various pros and cons. His verdict on Marxism: ‘Fatally flawed, but still
useful: theories of the firm, work, and technological progress.’
The worst flaw: ‘Above all, its
prediction that capitalism will collapse under its own weight has not come
true.’
Marx was not in the habit of ‘predicting’
anything, and certainly not that any capitalist ‘collapse’ is inevitable. Capital
will end with its expropriation from its owners by the proletariat, capital’s ‘gravediggers’,
but this is more of a threat and rallying-cry than a prediction. Otherwise capital as a system might linger
over a long period of time, but the proletariat is the only class or factor
that can destroy it. Marx was not a revolutionary activist for nothing. He saw
history as class struggle, and in our time the only means by which socialism
would come about. Marx did not predict when and where socialist revolution would come about. (In later life he
became interested in the revolutionary potential of the Russian peasantry and
even learned Russian from scratch to follow the literature more closely.)
Meanwhile, the idea that capitalism can destroy itself without class intervention
is contrary to Marx’s entire outlook. And such intervention is to be fought
for, not ‘predicted’. His critique of the capital system was to enable workers to understand its workings in its entirety: to fight your enemy, you must know it.
Chang: ‘The collapse of the socialist
bloc has revealed that the Marxian theory of how the alternative to capitalism
should be organised was highly inadequate. The list goes on.’ Not in this book.
(All citations from 131-132.) Marx spurned utopians with their theories of how
a future society should be created, keeping well away from such
prognostications himself. It was up to the workers to self-organize a new
society on the basis of ‘from each according to his abilities to each according
to his needs’. Marx’s ‘theory’ here is indeed highly inadequate because it
doesn’t exist and never did. Marx did not do fanciful system-building.
In any case the ‘socialist bloc’ was
state capitalist, not socialist. That is, it was an exploitative system.
Workers in Soviet Russia, like everywhere else, produced surplus value from
unpaid labour-time which accrued to state enterprise as opposed to private. After
the fall, in 1991, the transfer of state ownership to private was both swift
and corrupt.
Neither Lenin nor Trotsky had any
illusions that they were creating socialism in Russia after 1917. They looked
to impending Western socialist revolutions to give their own a kick start. When
these failed to attain ascendancy, Lenin and the Bolsheviks had to improvise in
a desperately isolated situation, the alternative being the anarchy of a power
vacuum. It was Stalin who drove through industrialisation, at a furious pace,
on the non-Marxist slogan of ‘socialism in one country’. At huge and tragic
human cost it worked: Russia was modernised to the point where it would defeat
Germany in World War II (and indeed send the first unmanned space vehicle,
Sputnik I, into orbit in 1957 – not the first ‘manned’ one, as Chang writes on
p. 95). But industrialisation was initially achieved on the basis of mass forced
labour, whether ‘free’ or enslaved. It was never socialism, let alone Marxian
socialism, whatever the ideology put forward.
Chang is reasonably informative on
some aspects of Marx’s contribution to ‘economics’ (though Marx's study remained within ‘political economy’, not the truncated form known to us as ‘economics’).
But, just as the word ‘critique’ appears in the title of his major
political economic writings, Marx was a forensic tearer-down of a system, not
the builder of a new one. For him socialism would be what the triumph of a
non-exploitative proletariat made it. And, to be frank, Chang’s conclusion on
Marx’s ‘flaws’ is shoddy thinking: raising an old canard that is easily
disposed of.
No comments:
Post a Comment